My contact detail is: joana.pedroso@law.gu.se.

This article builds on insights from my doctoral thesis (defended in March 2024) and provides an overview of how the European Union (EU) State Aid control system exerts a top-down impact on the fiscal autonomy of Member States (MS). By examining how the Court of Justice, the General Court, and the European Commission have interpreted State aid conditions across various fiscal contexts to curb anti-competitive and protectionist practices – including cases decided after my thesis was completed – the article highlights key developments that affect MS tax practices. Consequently, it seeks to offer a broader understanding of how the EU State Aid framework continues to shape both fiscal policymaking and practical tax measures at the national level.

1 Background

In this article, I provide an overview of how the European Union (EU) State aid control system1 impacts national fiscal measures, focusing mostly on how these measures grant, either de jure or de facto, selective advantageous tax treatment according to the relevant case law.2 The condition of a selective advantage is the most critical and debated aspect of State aid, as it involves interpreting the principle of equality within the context of Article 107(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (‘TFEU’) in specific cases.3

The State aid control system is complex and poses a significant challenge for academics, policymakers, tax law practitioners, and other stakeholders, as it requires them to be well-versed in its specific language and instrumentality, particularly in interpreting the selective advantage condition.4 The system has accumulated extensive and substantive case law over the past two decades, with the Commission playing an active and leading role in achieving this development.5 As a result, the impact of the State aid control system on national tax legislation is often difficult to predict, leading to low legal certainty regarding the compliance of the national fiscal measures with the prohibition set forth in Article 107(1) of the TFEU.

From a domestic tax law perspective, the State aid control system shapes fiscal measures through a top-down approach, i.e., through enforcing the prohibition in Article 107(1) of the TFEU. Each Commission decision or EU Court ruling legally binds the MS issuer of the aid, based on Article 288 of the TFEU. Beyond this effect, State aid decisions and rulings establish a precedent for other cases,6 thereby also fostering policy diffusion (when countries learn from one another’s experiences).7 While all these effects are integral to the interplay between the EU and its Member States (“MS”), I will not delve into them in detail here.8

This article has five sections. The first section is introductory. In section 2, I explain the concept of aid and how fiscal measures fit into this concept, including how this relates to the condition of being granted by a Member State or through State resources. In section 3, I focus on the selective advantage condition. Finally, I conclude this paper with some reflections in section 4.

By State aid control system, I mean the State aid primary laws (i.e., Articles 107–109 of the TFEU), secondary laws (e.g. Regulation 1589/2015), the Commission Guidelines and Notices on different subjects of State aid, the Commission’s State aid decisions, and the EU Courts State aid rulings.

This article was updated on September 18th, 2024, to include the ruling on the case C-465/20 P, Commission v Apple Sales International Ltd. and others. It is based on my thesis, which was updated up to May 31st, 2023, and was successfully defended in March 2024. Pedroso, J. (2024), Environmental Taxes from the EU State Aid Control System Perspective – A Legal Analysis of the Integration of Environmental Protection, Juridiska institutionens skriftserie, 043, e-copy available at .

Biondi, A. (2013), “State Aid is falling down, falling down: An analysis of the case law on the notion of Aid,” Common Market Law Review, 50(6), 1.719–1.743, in p. 1.733.

For instance, economic activities are often called operators, firms, or undertakings. Aldestam’s doctoral research focused primarily on the selective advantage condition due to its complexities. In Aldestam, M. (2004), EC State aid rules applied to taxes – An analysis of the selectivity criterion, Iustus förlag, Uppsala. See, among others, Bartosch, A. (2010), “Is there a need for a rule of reason in European State aid law? Or how to arrive at a coherent concept of selectivity?” Common Law Review, 47(3), pp. 729–752; and Blauberger, M. (2009), “From Negative to Positive Integration. European State Aid Control through Soft and Hard Law,” Paper to be presented EUSA Eleventh Biennial International Conference, Los Angeles, pp. 23–25.

The Commission’s dual role—both legislating on State aid matters and enforcing compliance with State aid rules—under Article 108 of the TFEU makes this EU institution partial to its own agenda. However, since MS agreed to the contents of the Lisbon Treaties, conferring powers and compromising to cooperate sincerely (based on Article 4 of the Treaty on EU, ‘TEU’), the duty to comply with Article 107(1) of the TFEU prohibition is inherent within the EU legal system the same way as the Commission’s dual role stated in Article 108 of the TFEU. See Englisch, J. (2024), “Sliding scales of review in State aid control of fiscal aid schemes,” (January 15, 2024), A Journey Through European and International Taxation – Liber Amicorum in Honour of Peter Essers, available at .

For instance, the first Commission State aid decision on a tax issue opens the door for this institution to explore similar issues in other Member States, e.g., the grant of State aid through tax rulings which is based on joined cases C-182/03 and C-217/03, Belgium v Commission. See also Commission Notice on the notion of State aid as referred in Article 107(1) of the TFEU (hereafter only ‘Notice’), OJ C 262, 19.7.2016, para. 169.

I discuss the effects of policy diffusion in my thesis, in subchapter 7.6, pp. 346–351 (footnote 2).

The reader is welcome to read my thesis, which is open-access and available online (footnote 2).

2 The Concept of Aid

2.1 The Cumulative Conditions to Classify a Measure as State Aid

Article 107(1) of the TFEU defines what constitutes State aid. It states:

“Save as otherwise provided in the Treaties, any aid granted by a Member State or through State resources in any form whatsoever which distorts or threatens to distort competition by favouring certain undertakings or the production of certain goods shall, in so far as it affects trade between Member States, be incompatible with the internal market.”

Based on its textual construction, the Court of Justice has extracted four cumulative conditions.9 They are:

  1. Granted by a Member State or through State resources;

  2. Distorts or threatens to distort competition;

  3. Favouring certain undertakings or the production of certain goods (or selective advantage);

  4. Affect trade between Member States.

Indeed, the State aid classification requires that all four conditions are fulfilled. In practice, the third condition (the selective advantage) predominantly spurs the court cases10 and scholarly debate.11 The key issue concerning the interpretation of this condition is how to establish the parameters that determine the comparability of taxpayers.12 Whether the measure grants a selective advantage depends on this comparability, which is often contentious and difficult to agree upon. I return to the selective advantage condition in section 3.

See in the joined cases C-20/15 P and C-21/15 P, Commission v World Duty-Free Group S.A. and others, para. 53, the Court of Justice’s explanation about the four conditions set out in Article 107(1) of the TFEU.

In the majority of preliminary rulings questioning the Court of Justice if the domestic tax in discussion is State aid or not, the legal debate is about the selective advantage condition. See, for instance, case C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipelines GmbH and Wietersdorfer & Peggauer Zementwerke GmbH v Finanzlandesdirektion für Kärnten (hereafter only Adria-Wien Pipeline GmbH), case C-159/01, Netherlands v Commission, case C-5/14, Kernkraftwerke Lippe-Ems GmbH v Hauptzollamt Osnabrück, case C-233/16, ANGED, joined cases C-234/16 and C-235/16, ANGED, joined cases C-236/16 and C-237/16, ANGED, and in joined cases C-105 to C-113/18, UNESA, among others.

See, among others, Bartosch, A. (2010), pp. 729–752 (footnote 4); and Blauberger, M. (2009), pp. 23–25 (footnote 4); Sutter, F. (2001), “The ‘Adria Wien Pipeline’ case and the State Aid provisions of the EC Treaty in tax matters,” European Taxation, 41(7), p. 241; Nicolaides, P. (2014), “A Surprising Interpretation of the Concept of Selectivity,” Lexxion Publishing, State Aid Uncovered, blog, 9 December 2014, among others.

The Commission is not allowed to compare MS’ tax regimes for the assessment of compliance with the State aid rule. I discuss this in section 4 of this article.

2.2 Formal and Substantial Effects

Understanding the concept of aid is critical. MS may have their tax discretion suppressed if their fiscal measures are classified as State aid and subjected to the EU State aid control system. Although EU case law has substantively developed this concept, uncertainties remain regarding which measures qualify as State aid and which do not. The concept of aid has been long established and developed. In 1961, the Court of Justice provided the following perspective on the issue:

“(…) The concept of aid is nevertheless wider than that of a subsidy because it embraces not only positive benefits, such as subsidies themselves, but also interventions which, in various forms, mitigate the charges which are normally included in the budget of an undertaking and which, without, therefore, being subsidies in the strict meaning of the word, are similar in character and have the same effect.”13

Fiscal measures are not subsidies in the sense that public money is paid directly to undertakings.14 State aiding through fiscal measures provides economic benefits to taxpayers-beneficiaries15 by, inter alia, reducing, not charging, delaying the tax burden due, or simply resulting in a taxable amount differently than others in a similar situation. Consequently, State aid in the form of fiscal measures is not only granted through exemptions but also through different tax results of corporate income taxation. Below are some examples of advantages that could fall under the prohibition of Article 107(1) of the TFEU.

  1. Progressive rates and two differentiated flat rates;16

  2. Any tax benefit, such as deductions, reductions, credits, exemptions, deferrals, carry-forwards, carry-backs, etc.17

  3. Accept intra-group transactions that lead to no or low corporate income tax due.18

  4. Not properly applying anti-abuse law.19

The beneficiaries of State aid fiscal measures are relieved from paying taxes as they would normally owe, either because there was a reduction through an exemption or through a combination of rules that resulted in a lower tax amount due. In this sense, fiscal measures have similar effects to subsidies because, in both cases, the beneficiaries of the aid measure gain economically—either by receiving money (subsidies) or keeping money in the company’s account through tax relief (fiscal measures or taxation).

Since 1974, the Court of Justice has consistently emphasized that interpreting Article 107(1) of the TFEU necessitates considering the actual effects of the fiscal measure in question.20 This suggests that even if the textual formulation of the tax law does not meet the formal conditions of State aid, it should still be considered State aid if it substantially fulfills those conditions. Without regard to such substantial (de facto) effects, Article 107(1) of the TFEU would lack force in protecting the functioning of the internal market against illegal State measures that protect domestic sectors and are anti-competitive.21

In case C-30/59, De Gezamenlijke Steenkolenmijnen in Limburg v High Authority of the European Coal and Steel Community, p. 19.

See the explanation of this term in footnote 4.

By beneficiaries of State aid through fiscal measures it means both the direct and indirect beneficiaries. In the case of indirect taxation, e.g., such as VAT, the tax burden reduced is passed along the chain to the final consumer who pays for the tax and internalizes that cost. Both the company, acting as the tax collector, and the consumer, paying for the tax, are the beneficiaries of the reduction. However, Article 107(1) of the TFEU only targets the selective advantageous tax treatment for undertakings, i.e., economic activities. Hence, the companies collecting the taxes are the ones affected by that prohibition. See further discussion concerning the beneficiaries when aid is to be recovered in Kokott, J. (2022), EU Tax Law A Handbook, Hart Publishing, Kent House, Chawley Park, pp. 188–189 (§ 144).

See the discussion in the case C-596/19 P, Commission v Hungary about progressive rates. In my view, the Court of Justice never disregarded the possibility of progressive rates granting advantage set out in Article 107(1) of the TFEU but how the Commission assessed it. See also, in joined cases C-164/15 P and C-165/15 P, Commission v Ireland, Aer Lingus Ltd, and Ryanair Designated Activity Company, the discussion about two differentiated flat rates, from which the lower rate was considered an advantage granted selectively.

The Commission Notice on the notion of State aid as referred to in Article 107(1) of the TFEU, para. 68, explains how the concept of tax advantage is far-reaching. In the Commission’s words: “The precise form of the measure is also irrelevant in establishing whether it confers an economic advantage on the undertaking. (…), but relief from economic burdens can also constitute an advantage. The latter is a broad category which comprises any mitigation of charges normally included in the budget of an undertaking. This covers all situations in which economic operators are relieved of the inherent costs of their economic activities. For instance, if a Member State pays part of the costs of the employees of a specific undertaking, it relieves that undertaking from costs that are inherent of its economic activities. (…).”

See in joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europé, Ireland, Luxembourg v Commission, and in joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group).

In joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group), paras. 133–150.

In case 173/73, Italy v Commission, p. 718, para 13.

Nowag, J. (2016), Environmental Integration in Competition and Free Movement Laws, Oxford University Press, p. 181.

2.3 Forms of granting aid

Since the classification of a fiscal measure as State aid depends on whether it satisfies the conditions set out in Article 107(1) of the TFEU—conditions that must be interpreted by examining both the formal and substantive effects of the measure—it logically follows that there is no specific format required for granting aid. Any form of aid may qualify, as long as the measure meets the stipulated conditions. Consequently, legislators’ untold intentions to protect a domestic sector or industry from the highly competitive internal market are often caught in such an analysis of the measure’s substantial effects. Based on this view, below is a list of examples of fiscal measures that could be classified as State aid:

  1. A tax law or several tax laws of different statuses encompassing the tax regime that formally and/or substantially meets the State aid conditions.22

  2. Tax authorities’ tax rulings, decisions, settlements, and similar actions interpreting the tax laws referred to in the previous point (1) and grant a tax treatment that meets the State aid conditions.23

  3. Soft laws (e.g., guidelines, notices, etc.) issued by a tax agency or competent authority that has tax jurisdiction over the fiscal matter, clarifying the interpretation of the tax regime referred to in point (1) to concrete cases, forming part of the MS’s practice. Additionally, they meet the State aid conditions.24

  4. Case law of the MS concerned that meet the State aid conditions.25 In this case, a national court ruling, deciding upon the interpretation of a tax regime could be the grantor of State aid.

There is a procedural distinction between ad hoc aid (individual aid) and aid schemes, and their difference can be tricky to grasp in this general discussion.26 Tax rulings and settlements may seem like typical examples of individual aid because they relate to a specific company’s circumstance and taxation. However, that may not be the case if the granting of State aid, mainly the selective advantageous tax treatment, arises from the interpretation of the tax rules of the MS concerned, meaning that it is a simple tax law in practice i.e., its substantial effects. This is particularly relevant because the burden of proof for individual aid differs from that for aid schemes.27

In individual aid cases, the Commission only needs to show the existence of tax advantage because the selectivity of the beneficiary is logical, based on how the aid is granted.28 A tax ruling can only benefit the company that requested such an administrative decision. In aid schemes, the Commission has an extensive burden of proof of the selective effect, which is about determining who is or should be comparable for specific tax purposes.29 I get back to this discussion in section 3.

See, for instance, an example of such case in C-487/06 P, British Aggregates Association v Commission and U.K.

See, for instance, an example of such case in joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europé, Ireland, Luxembourg v Commission.

Note that this point was intrinsic in the discussion in the joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie Group), para. 121, which is posterior to my thesis timeframe. When the Court of Justice explains the following view: “The Commission may depart from that interpretation only if it is able to establish, on the basis of reliable and consistent evidence that has been the subject of that exchange of arguments, that another interpretation prevails in the case-law or the administrative practice of that Member State.” My interpretation is that the administrative practice of the MS can also relate to soft laws used as legal support to issue tax rulings.

Ibid idem. However, different from the previous discussion, the national case law is explicitly mentioned in that Court of Justice ruling.

In the Commission Guidelines on State aid for climate, environmental protection and energy 2022 (or simply ‘CEEAG’), OJ C 80, 18.2.2022, p. 1–89, paras. 18, 19(1). Also, in joined cases C-20/15 and C-21/15 P, Commission v World Duty-Free Group S.A. and others, p. 55.

In case C-15/14 P, Commission v MOL Magyar Olaj- és Gázipari Nyrt, para. 60.

Ibid idem.

Ibid, para. 59.

2.4 State Aid or Union Aid?

Fiscal measures can only constitute State aid if the grantor of the aid is a MS. In this sense, the fiscal measure in question that grants a selective advantageous tax treatment must be granted by a Member State (part of the first State aid condition) and not by the EU. If the selective advantageous tax treatment arises e.g., from an EU Directive, it is Union aid. Hence, it cannot be forbidden by Article 107(1) of the TFEU. So, we need to know whether the fiscal measure in question was harmonized by EU law. That is, if the Council, acting unanimously, passed a fiscal measure based on Articles 113, 115, 192(2)(a), or 194(3) of the TFEU.

From a national tax law perspective, the tax jurisdiction and discretion within the MS territory are usually determined by its constitutional law or equivalent. Hence, a municipal tax law, lawfully issued by municipal legislators who hold such tax jurisdiction based on the national law, falls within the meaning of the condition granted by a Member State set out in Article 107(1) of the TFEU. The same rationale applies to regional, national, federal, and other divisions of tax jurisdictions within a country.30 Furthermore, it includes tax authorities’ discretion from all diverse jurisdictions within the country interpreting tax rules that grant State aid.31 Tax authorities may also fulfill the condition granted by a Member State, alongside tax legislators explained previously. The lack of EU tax laws on specific fiscal issues entails that MS remain with tax discretion and sovereignty on those issues. However, the prohibition in Article 107(1) of the TFEU and the Commission’s extensive leeway granted by Article 108 of the TFEU is the Commission’s large door to enter and supersede the MS domain.

When a fiscal matter is approved at the EU level, the MS’ tax discretion and sovereignty are fully or partially limited by that EU law, depending on the type of law (e.g., a regulation or a directive) and its content (e.g., if it determines specific taxpayers and tax objects or not).32 In this case, the MS can only be liable for the aiding measure or action if the State aid conditions–effects arose from the margin of discretion not limited by that EU law. In this sense, the MS might grant State aid if it exercises its tax discretion when implementing or applying the EU law, which did not remove that part of the MS’ tax discretion. In this case, the MS is the grantor of the State aid.33 The MS is also considered the grantor of the aid when the EU fiscal law did not intend such an aid result, which was delivered when implementing or applying that EU law.34 Hence, when the EU law explicitly discriminates against comparable taxpayers, it constitutes a case of Union aid and not State aid.

From a tax law perspective, the principle of legality plays a key role in this discussion. Tax laws, rulings, and other actions concerning tax imposition should be prescribed in the laws of the MS concerned. That is why fiscal measures easily meet the first part of the first State aid condition granted by a Member State. Moreover, this principle also delimits the assessment of the selective advantage condition, which I return to in section 4.

Finally, the logic of through State resources (the second part of the first State aid condition) is straightforward. When a selective advantageous tax treatment is granted, it causes a renouncement of revenue that the MS concerned should have collected but does not do due to the aid.35

See in case C-78/76, Firma Steinike und Weinlig, Hamburg, v Germany, para. 21, p. 611; in the case C-248/84, Germany v Commission, para. 17; in the joined cases C-67/85, C-68/85 and C-70/85, Van der Kooy v Commission, paras. 35–36; and, in the case C-303/88, Italy v Commission, paras. 11–12. In case C-248/84, Germany v Commission, para. 17.

Ibid idem.

Based on Article 288 of the TFEU concerning the legal effects of EU actions and the powers conferred to the EU divided into different levels of competence in Articles 2 to 6 of the TFEU.

See this discussion in Englisch, J. (2013), “EU State Aid Rules Applied to Indirect Tax Measures,” EC Tax Review, 22(1), pp. 9–18.

Ibid idem.

In joined cases C-20/15 P and C-21/15 P, Commission v World Duty Free Group S.A. and others, para. 53.

2.5 Compatible Aid or incompatible Aid?

The State aid classification under Article 107(1) of the TFEU is not final. Article 107(2) and (3) of the TFEU allow MS to implement State aid measures (i.e., compatible aid) when they pursue certain internal market objectives listed therein. Permission under Article 107(2) of the TFEU is automatic. Permission under Article 107(3) of the TFEU requires monitoring and control by the Commission through the regime outlined in Article 108(1) to (3) of the TFEU, Regulation 1589/2015, and other relevant legislation.36 However, the State aid classification under Article 107(1) of the TFEU is the most critical event. It is the moment when the EU has discretion over the domestic fiscal measure to ensure the Article’s prohibition.

Regulation 1589/2015 laying down detailed rules for the application of Article 108 of the TFEU, OJ L 248, 24.9.2015, p. 9–29. For instance, Commission Regulation (EU) No 651/2014 of 17 June 2014 declaring certain categories of aid compatible with the internal market in application of Articles 107 and 108 of the Treaty, OJ L 187, 26.6.2014, p. 1–78 (consolidated version 02014R0651 — EN — 01.07.2023 — 006.001) or simply ‘GBER’.

3 The selective advantage condition

3.1 Method to assess the condition

As the selective advantage condition is the key factor in determining whether fiscal measures qualify as State aid, I will now explain the Court of Justice’s general interpretation of this condition. The Court of Justice has established a three-step approach to assess the selective advantage condition (i.e., favouring certain undertakings or the production of certain goods), which is the predominant debate in State aid rulings concerning fiscal measures because it concerns the comparability of taxpayers. The tax advantage is only problematic from a State aid point of view if it is granted on a selective basis.37 Otherwise, it is deemed general as a natural feature of tax systems, e.g., deductions, reductions, exemptions, credits, and any other type of economic benefit granted on a general and non-selective basis. To assess this condition, the Court of Justice stipulated the following three-step approach:

  1. Identify the ordinary or ‘normal’ tax system applicable in the MS concerned (hereafter, the identification of the reference tax regime).38

  2. Demonstrate that the tax measure at issue is a derogation from that ordinary system, discriminates or puts beneficiaries of the measure in a better position, in so far as it differentiates between operators who, in the light of the objective pursued by that ordinary tax system, are in a comparable factual and legal situation (hereafter, the identification of the circle of comparable undertakings).39

  3. Verify if the prima facie selective treatment can be justified on the nature or general structure of the system of which the measures form part (hereafter, the justification possibilities).40

In the following sections, I explain, in general terms, the logic of each step and how the Court of Justice case law evolved until recently on the issues raised there.

In the joined cases C-20/15 and C-21/15 P, Commission v World Duty-Free Group S.A. and others, para. 56.

Ibid, paras. 57–58.

Ibid idem.

Ibid idem.

3.1.1 First step: the reference tax regime

A. General understanding of the reference tax regime

In this first step, the Commission or the National Court (as another State aid interpreter in domestic disputes involving Article 107(1) of the TFEU) should identify the reference tax regime.41 This first step establishes a benchmark for the objective and logic of the tax regime, allowing for an analysis of the circle of comparable taxpayers in the second step.42 The reference regime gives logic to the tax imposition and provides information about how the tax operates.43 As a result, it defines the logic of tax burden distribution, the identification of taxpayers, and other key aspects of tax imposition. An error in the reference regime assessment might undermine a State aid assessment entirely.44 Below, I raise some questions that could be helpful for this analysis.

  1. What is the tax object and taxable event?

  2. How is the tax formulated in terms of tax rates, tax base, and tax benefits applicable (e.g., exemptions and rebates)?

  3. Who is the measure taxing? Identify the taxpayers.

  4. Why are taxpayers being taxed this way? Identify the objective of the tax, including the objective of the tax benefits that give logic to the imposition.

These questions help in finding the reference regime. In the following section (B), I answer them using the Swedish income tax law as an example to clarify the nuances of this first step. Note that this is not a State aid analysis per se.

Also called synonymously the normal/ordinary/common tax system/framework.

In joined cases C-51/19 P and C-64/19 P, World Duty Free Group and Spain v Commission, para. 60.

In para. 133 of the Commission Notice on the notion of State aid.

In case C-203/16 P, Andres (insolvency of Heitkamp BauHolding) v Commission, para. 107.

B. Example of a reference regime: The Swedish Income Tax Regime

The Swedish Income Tax Regime is determined in Law 1999:1229 (hereafter only ‘IL’). Chapter 1 of the IL defines what the law is about, i.e., tax on income (§ 1). It establishes which income individuals and legal persons must pay tax on. Hence, §§ 3–4 gives a partial answer to question (a) since more details of what the IL is taxing are found in other parts of that law.

How the tax on different incomes should be accounted for in the case of individuals are set out in Chapter 1, respectively in §§ 5–6, 8–11, 13, Chapter 3, Chapter 65, and others Chapters, and for corporate tax in Chapter 1 §§ 7–11, 15, Chapter 6, Chapter 65, and other Chapters. For instance, Chapter 8 establishes which income is tax-free. Chapter 9 determines which expenses are not deductible. Chapters 10 to 12 determine specific details of the tax regime concerning the income from services, while Chapters 13 to 40 determine specific details of the tax regime concerning the income from business activities. Income on capital is particularly governed by Chapters 41 to 55. Different types of tax benefits are mostly governed by Chapters 62 to 64 and 67. Consequently, a general answer to question (b) concerning the IL lies in the rules found in those mentioned Chapters.

The answer to question (c), i.e., who the IL is taxing are the taxpayers identified in different places of that law. Chapters 3, 4, 5–7 define different taxpayers covered by the IL.

The last question (d) can be trickier, i.e., why the IL is taxing this way. The objectives of the IL may not be necessarily found explicitly in its provisions. It could be more clearly defined in the preparatory work of the IL or implicit in the tax choice (a tax on income to generate revenues for the State). The logic of the tax regime (i.e., the why) is the State aid question. It is about what the tax regime is versus what it ought to be based on the objectives of the tax measure.

Consider a hypothetical situation where the IL excludes deceased estates from its tax imposition, meaning it does not reference them at all. From a tax law perspective grounded in the principle of legality, this omission could imply that deceased estates are lawfully outside the scope of the IL and, therefore, are not subject to income tax. However, from a State aid perspective, the EU Commission might view the IL as too narrow in scope.45 The Commission could interpret the IL’s inherent objectives—such as those outlined in preparatory works—to suggest that deceased estates should logically fall within its tax imposition. In such a case, the reference regime is not simply identified but re-determined based on what the tax law should encompass rather than what it currently does.46 That said, unless deceased estates qualify as economic activities, they will remain outside the scope of Article 107(1) of the TFEU. Thus, the first step involves not only determining the reference regime based on the principle of legality in tax law but also analyzing what the regime should ideally include, considering the law’s underlying objectives.

Based on C-5/14, Kernkraftwerke Lippe-Ems GmbH v Hauptzollamt Osnabrück, para. 76, which benchmarked the narrow scope view for the first time. See Nicolaides, P. (2022), “A Non-Selective Financial Tax with a Narrow Scope,” Lexxion Publishing, State Aid Uncovered, blog, 18 January 2022, available at .

Based on case C-106/09 P and C-107/09 P, Commission v Gibraltar, then on case C-5/14, Kernkraftwerke Lippe-Ems GmbH v Hauptzollamt Osnabrück, para. 76. See further in Rossi-Maccanico, P. (2012), “Gibraltar: Beyond the Pillars of Hercules of Selectivity,” European State Aid Law Quarterly,11(2), pp. 443–48; Lang, J. (2012), “The Gibraltar state aid and taxation judgment a methodical revolution,” European State Aid Law Quarterly, 11(4), pp. 805–812; Traversa, E. and Flamini, A. (2015), “Fighting harmful tax competition through EU state aid law: will the hardening of soft law suffice,” European State Aid Law Quarterly, 14(3), pp. 328–329; in Biondi, A., (2013), pp. 1719–1743 (footnote 3), in my thesis, Pedroso J (2024), pp. 156–159 (footnote 2), among others.

C. De facto reference regime

As the example above elucidates, while identifying the de jure reference regime is relatively straightforward and grounded in the principle of legality, determining the de facto reference regime is more difficult. A typical example arises when the tax law appears objective from a formal perspective, but in practice, the combination of rules results in a selective advantageous tax treatment that contradicts the law’s intended objectives–this was evident in the Gibraltar case, which benchmarked this view.47

Similarly, a tax regime with an overly narrow scope may seem objective upon formal analysis, yet in practice, it excludes taxpayers who should logically fall within its scope.48 In both instances, the de facto reference regime should align proportionally with the fundamental objectives of the law, meaning those excluded taxpayers should have been formally included in the tax imposition. Note that such conclusions about the reference regime only arise from interpreting the rule on State aid (i.e., Article 107(1) of the TFEU) in the context of national tax law.

Ibid idem.

Based on cases C-5/14, Kernkraftwerke Lippe-Ems GmbH v Hauptzollamt Osnabrück; case C-233/16, joined cases C-234/16 and C-235/16, and joined cases C-236/16 and C-237/16, ANGED; and joined cases C-105/18 to C-113/18, UNESA.

D. Geographic reference regime

It could be that the reference tax regime is delimited by a geographic area–jurisdiction. A typical example is when regions of MS have total discretion on the issue being taxed (e.g., a state within a federal MS) or an overseas territory of a MS. In this case, the geographic tax law could be the reference regime instead of the one of the MS concerned, provided it fulfills three conditions, the so-called three-autonomy test developed in the Azores ruling.49 They are: (1) institutional, (2) procedural, and (3) financial autonomies. In my thesis, I explained the following view about each autonomy test:

“Institutional autonomy is the legal circumstance where the tax legislators have autonomous tax power, defined by the laws of the Member State in question, which grants them total discretion to decide politically, legally, economically, and administratively the design features of the regional tax law.

“Procedural autonomy” is the circumstance in which the central government does not have the power, i.e., legitimacy, to intervene in the tax directly.

Financial autonomy is the circumstance where the economic situation of the undertakings of the region means they cannot receive public benefits (whether tax exemptions or subsidies) from other areas, or from the central government of the Member State.”50

Hence, if the regional tax law fulfills these three levels, it is the reference tax regime.

In case C-88/03, Portugal v Commission, paras. 67–68.

In my thesis, Pedroso (2024), pp. 161–162 (footnote 2).

E. The Objective and Logic of the Reference Tax Regime Is Found in the MS’s System

The Court of Justice’s latest rulings limited the Commission’s discretion in assessing the reference regime based on the previous section discussion (about the determination of a de facto reference regime). The Commission must make an objective assessment of the MS’s measure in question and start from the reference regime appointed by that MS,51 and base its assessment on the laws of the MS concerned.52 The Commission does not have the discretion to question the choice of instrument (e.g., a turnover tax) and its features (e.g., progressive rates) of the MS based on a different logic than that found in the tax system of the MS concerned. For instance, the fact that other MS have turnover taxes on a flat rate cannot be questioned by the Commission because such tax choices fall under the MS’ tax discretion.53 Consequently, MS tax systems are not comparable for assessing the selective advantage condition.

Only the laws of the MS under scrutiny are relevant for determining the reference regime. The Commission can only disregard the MS’s appointed reference regime if its practices, i.e., national case law and tax administration’s practice, show a different interpretation than the one informed by that MS.54 Consequently, this is an interpretation and application of the principle of legality within the State aid law, where it is only allowed to discuss a de facto reference regime when the objective of the tax regime and the practice of the MS concerned supports this view.55

In joined cases C-51/19 P and C-64/19 P, World Duty Free Group and Spain v Commission, para. 62.

In joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europe, Ireland, Luxembourg v Commission, pp. 92–105.

In case T-20/17, Hungary v Commission, paras. 11–12, and 82, C-596/19 P, Commission v Hungary, para. 46.

In joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group), paras. 120–121. See also Pedroso, J. (2024), “Commentary on the Judgement of the European Court of Justice in joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group) – the limits of the Commission’s discretion,” Svensk Skattetidning, 2024, 2, pp. 122–138.

In case C-596/19 P, Commission v Hungary, para. 48; and joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europé, Ireland, Luxembourg v Commission, paras. 96–97. See also in Pedroso, J. (2023), “Commentary on the Judgement, in joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P Fiat Chrysler Finance Europe: State aid in the form of tax rulings,” Svensk Skattetidning, 2023, 1, pp. 61–68.

3.1.2 Second step: determining the advantage and the circle of comparable undertakings

A. General understanding

In this second step, the State aid interpreter must find that the tax advantage is conferred selectively benefiting certain taxpayers or tax objects while excluding others (explicitly or implicitly) who are in a comparable factual and legal situation.56 If the advantage is considered general (not selective), then the measure is deemed general and, consequently, does not qualify as State aid. However, before any selectivity effect can be assessed, the existence of a tax advantage must first be established. Note, however, that if the advantage sum is not over 300.000 euros per single undertaking and for up to three years, it is the case to assess whether the De Minimis Regulation applies, thereby automatically allowing the aid imposition.57

The analysis of advantages varies between direct and indirect taxation. Indirect taxes typically grant an advantage by either excluding certain undertakings from the tax scope or by applying some normal rate payment reduction (e.g., partial or full exemption) or other benefits (e.g., deferral, credit, etc.).58

In the context of direct taxes, especially for advantages not granted through typical tax reductions (i.e., through a tax deduction or credit), the analysis of the advantage becomes more complex, particularly when it involves a combination of rules that grants a de facto selective advantage.59 In recent case law, particularly regarding State aid granted to multinationals through advance tax rulings related to corporate income tax, the analysis of the advantage effect became extremely difficult because it requires an objective analysis of a combination of complex rules that lead to a de facto reduction of the corporate tax base.60 Such an analysis (concerning what the interpretation of such complex rules is or ought to be) is constricted to the MS laws and praxis.61

The identification of selective treatment requires a difficult examination of the principles of equality and proportionality,62 aiming to identify instances where comparable taxpayers are not taxed in the same way.63 In my view, answering one of the following questions can be particularly helpful in carrying out this part of the analysis:

  1. Who should be the logical taxpayers of the normal tax burden and taxpayers-beneficiaries of the lower tax burden, based on the objective of the reference regime? This question is relevant in case the advantage is not granted through a combination of rules.

  2. Based on the Member State’s reference regime and practice concerning the interpretation of those rules, is it possible to find a de facto selective treatment? This question is relevant in case the advantage is granted through a combination of rules.

A straightforward example of how the objective of the tax influences such types of taxpayers’ choices is the case of energy taxes. An energy tax commonly has a tax base measured in kilowatt-hour (kWh) of energy consumed. Its objective is to tax the consumption of electricity. From this perspective, any energy consumer is a taxpayer. Individuals and businesses consume energy for different purposes. They might be regarded as non-comparable by legislators since the purpose of their energy use differs, without raising State aid issues (individuals and businesses do not compete). However, differentiated tax treatment among businesses cannot escape the State aid classification as energy consumption is indifferent to who consumes energy per kWh (the tax base).64

Despite this, from a State aid law perspective, the energy tax cannot create differentiated values among economic activities and thereby have different sectors or industries paying a different price for the kWh of energy consumed. Article 107(1) of the TFEU does not cover individuals and households, only businesses of any kind, although an autonomous service provider individual can be an undertaking through that provision.65 Hence, it protects the functioning of the internal market from anticompetitive or protectionist measures affecting economic activities comparable based on the logic of the tax under scrutiny. If the energy tax would grant exemptions, reductions, and any other type of tax benefit to specific economic activities, it is likely State aid. However, if it reduces the tax burden based on the energy source because of their different climate impact, then this conclusion could differ, depending on the EU law on the subject, since such reduction would be aiming to protect the environment.66

Without extending the discussion, the objectives of the tax law and the MS’s interpretation of the reference regime’s objectives are critical to determining who is comparable and should be paying equal levels of tax, thereby assessing possible breach of the principle of equality from an EU law perspective.67

Unlike the free movement provisions and Article 110 of the TFEU, the principle of proportionality is not a legal mechanism to justify when the measure breaches the principle of equality. In the interpretation of Article 107(1) of the TFEU, the principle of proportionality is a balancing between the measure’s objectives and the taxpayers’ tax treatment. Consequently, the principle of proportionality functions as a coherence test of the breach or respect to the principle of equality.68 It serves to assess whether the measure grants a selective advantageous tax treatment in the first place. Together, the principles of equality and proportionality establish the logic and coherence of the tax, particularly how the tax burden is distributed among taxpayers based on the objective it pursues.69

In joined cases C-20/15 and C-21/15 P, Commission v World Duty-Free Group S.A. and others, para. 54.

Commission Regulation (EU) 2023/2831 of 13 December 2023 on the application of Articles 107 and 108 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to de minimis aid, C/2023/9700, OJ L, 2023/2831, in Article 3(2).

See, for instance, cases mentioned in footnote 48. Also, in case C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipeline GmbH.

See Lind, Y. (2022), “The Fundamental of Tax Incentives”, Skatterett, 42, pp. 23–25, particularly her discussion about tax shelter that would deliver a similar result as the de facto selectivity effect of direct taxation discussed here.

See, for instance, joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europé, Ireland, Luxembourg v Commission; in joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group).

Ibid idem. In the most recent judgment of the Court of Justice Grand Chamber (in case C-465/20 P, Commission v Apple Sale International Ltd. And others, paras. 73–83), the judgment quotes ten paragraphs in a row concerning the joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Engie group, paras. 104–114, which also repeats several paragraphs of the joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance Europé, and others v Commission, paras. 65–69, 71–74.

In Aldestam, M. (2005), p. 17 (footnote 4), Biondi, A. (2013), p. 1.733 (footnote 3); Cisotta, R. (2016), “Criterion of Selectivity,” In Chapter 4, in State Aid Law of the European Union, Editors Hofmann, H. C. H., and Micheau, C., Oxford University Press, ebook, p. 137.

In joined cases C-51/19 P and C-64/19 P, World Duty Free Group and Spain v Commission, para. 99.

C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipeline GmbH, paras. 50–52.

See case C-172/03, Wolfgang Heiser v Finanzamt Innsbruck.

See reflection in this regard in my thesis, p. 165–167 (footnote 2).

In Biondi, A., (2013), p. 1.733 (footnote 3); in Cisotta, R. (2016), p. 137 (footnote 62); and in Aldestam, M. (2004), p. 17 (footnote 4).

Based on my thesis’ findings, pp. 177–180 (footnote 2).

Ibid idem.

B. The selectivity of differentiated rates (e.g., progressive or two flat rates)

Since MS have the discretion to choose the fiscal instruments they deem appropriate to address the objectives of their taxes–– including the tax features and instrumental aspects–– assessing the selectivity of differentiated rates can be challenging, particularly when their discretion has not been limited by EU law.70 Progressive rates and two different flat rates are not advantages per Article 107(1) of the TFEU unless they are granted selectively, i.e., discriminatorily. In this case of selectivity, the objective (aim) of the tax cannot always justify the thresholds that objectively determine the imposition of lower or higher rates.71

For instance, a flight tax on passengers should not present differentiated tax rates for those flying to different destinations within the EU if it only aims to raise revenues.72 This logic would change if the tax was imposed with the main objective of protecting the environment by taxing emissions generated by flights that contribute to climate change. In this case, progressive rates would be more logical and coherent with that objective than a flat rate, which would not internalize the heavier emissions longer destinations flights reproduce.73

That is, when the EU legislates through Articles 113, 115, 192(2)(a) and 194(3) of the TFEU.

See case C-596/19 P, Commission v Hungary, where the Commission discussed progressive rates.

Conclusion based on joined cases C-164/15 P and C-165/15 P, Commission v Ireland, Aer Lingus Ltd, and Ryanair Designated Activity Company.

See reflections about the Swedish flight taxes in Lind, Y. (2021) “Designing Aviation Taxes Within the EU–Chartering Ongoing Challenges and Proposing Future Solutions,” Florida Tax Review, 24(2), pp. 784–827, and in subchapter 7.6 of my thesis (footnote 2).

C. Selectivity of tax benefits (e.g., exemptions)

Another common feature of tax systems is the provision of tax benefits. Deductions, reductions, exemptions, deferrals, credits, rebates, and other types of tax benefits are a normal part of tax systems, a priori, not State aid. However, the State aid interpreter must find that there is a selective treatment for the granting of such tax benefits to classify the fiscal measure as State aid.

In this context, even two sectors that do not directly compete could be comparable undertakings. In the case of energy taxes, all business activities are comparable undertakings based on the objective of taxing energy consumption.74 Consequently, if industries of one sector are relieved from the normal tax burden of energy taxation, this relief is selective. Moreover, if only one undertaking receives the tax benefits, it also suffices to meet the condition.75

See again case C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipeline GmbH, paras. 50–52.

Case C-88/03, Portugal (Azores) and others v Commission, para. 91.

D. Selectivity in corporate income taxation through advance tax rulings

After the Court of Justice issued several judgments on advance tax rulings decided by tax authorities for multinational companies—rulings which the Commission perceived as State aid but were overturned by the Court—two key reflections are pertinent to this discussion.76 First, the fact that advance tax rulings are issued by tax authorities on an individual basis—specifically to the company seeking such decisions, providing legal certainty and predictability regarding its corporate income tax in a particular country—does not necessarily mean they constitute individual aid.77 Second, unless the tax law was formally and clearly written to benefit specific economic activities, the tax rulings interpreting them into a concrete case should not be considered a case of individual aid. The Commission must show that the tax ruling grants a lower tax burden than other companies received in a similar legal and factual situation. This is a clear conclusion after the Fiat Group and Engie Group tax rulings disputed as State aid.78

The Commission spurred the discussion and, thereby, the construction of general parameters to classifying tax rulings as State aid, even though in the Fiat and Engie cases, the Commission failed to prove the selective tax treatment of these measures. The lessons I draw from these cases is that the Commission must request the MS concerned to provide information about its administrative practice (other tax rulings, guidelines, etc.) and case law on the interpretation of the relevant laws upon which the tax ruling is based.79 It is likely that the Commission must request the MS to provide other tax rulings to analyze whether the relevant tax laws were interpreted differently, incoherently and disproportionately, thereby granting a selective tax treatment.

See in Pedroso, J. (2023), pp. 61–68 (footnote 55); and Pedroso, J. (2024), pp. 122–138 (footnote 54); also, in Pedroso’s thesis, pp. 217–219 (footnote 2).

See again 2.3. Forms of granting aid.

In joined cases C-885/19 P and C-898/19 P, Fiat Chrysler Finance, paras. 103–105, and in joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group), paras. 123–128 (when the advantage was not even properly identified to follow the analysis of the selectivity of the tax ruling).

In joined cases C-451/21 P and C-454/21 P, Luxembourg v Commission (Engie group), paras. 121–122.

E. Selective tax treatment when not applying anti-abuse rules in tax law

In the Engie case, the question of whether failing to apply an anti-abuse law could constitute State aid was addressed for the first time.80 The Court of Justice did not dismiss the possibility that omitting an anti-abuse provision in a corporate income tax ruling could result in a selectively advantageous tax treatment.81 However, due to the Commission’s incorrect conclusion about the reference tax regime, the legal basis for its selectivity analysis in this part was flawed and, therefore, could not be validated by the Court of Justice (as the General Court wrongfully did).82 Nonetheless, it is a benefit to not have anti-abuse rules applied on a concrete case, but in this example, like the previous one discussed in section D, the Commission would need to see in the MS practice that it deviated from its usual interpretation, thereby granting a selective advantageous tax treatment.83 The same rationale also applies to other similar rules in tax law, such as Controlled Foreign Corporation (‘CFC’) rules.84

Ibid, paras. 133–160.

Ibid idem.

Ibid, paras. 155–157.

See input in Pedroso, J. (2024) referred to in footnote 54.

See in cases T-363/19 and T-456/19, United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland, and others v Commission.

3.1.3 Justification

The last step is strictly applicable. It concerns the possibilities of justifying a fiscal measure that grants, a priori, a selective advantageous tax treatment. The latter could be accepted and, thereby, classified as non-state aid if the discriminatory treatment was proportional––an interpretation of the proportionality principle similar to other TFEU rules––aiming to address one of the following circumstances:85

  1. fight fraud or tax evasion,

  2. the need to consider specific accounting requirements,

  3. administrative manageability,

  4. the principle of tax neutrality,

  5. the progressive nature of income tax and its redistributive purpose,

  6. the need to avoid double taxation and

  7. the objective of optimizing the recovery of fiscal debts.

Fiscal measures hardly pass this step, and the Court of Justice quickly dismisses such justifications because they are often just hiding the protectionist intentions of the legislators.86 The majority of cases are solved––relieved from the State aid classification or classified as State aid––in the first and second steps of the selective advantage condition assessment. In the case of a State aid classification, only the Commission and the Council, in specific circumstances, are allowed by Article 108(3) of the TFEU to classify State aid measures as compatible with the internal market per Article 107(3) of the TFEU. Note that the classification of compatible with the internal market per Article 107(2) of the TFEU is automatic.

In Commission Notice on the notion of State aid, para. 139.

See, for instance, in case C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipeline GmbH, paras. 51–54.

4 Final Considerations

Given how the State aid control system works, it is not surprising that the Commission spurs significant developments in the field of taxation by enforcing the prohibition under Article 107(1) of the TFEU, which prevents Member States from granting State aid.87 When a fiscal matter is not harmonized via Articles 113, 114(2), 115, 192(2)(a), and 194(3) of the TFEU, the only way to address it at the EU level is through the negative harmonization of the TFEU rules. As it is well-known, this can be achieved through various legal avenues other than through State aid surveillance, such as through the free movement provisions or the prohibition under Article 110 of the TFEU.

Specifically, regarding the State aid control system, the interpretation of the selective advantage condition under Article 107(1) of the TFEU in relation to fiscal measures has become highly difficult. In the most recent ruling, delivered on 10 September 2024, the Court of Justice confirmed that Apple Group’s corporate tax arrangement, endorsed by Ireland through an advance tax ruling, constituted unlawful State aid.88 It is no surprise that State aid can be granted through an advance tax ruling, as I discussed in section 2.3 Forms of granting aid. The significant development here is that this is the first major case in terms of economic values in which the Court of Justice did not annul the Commission’s selective advantage assessment. Consequently, the Court’s final judgment on matter89 requires Apple Group to recover (repay) the unlawful State aid received from Ireland, along with interest, amounting to over 13 billion euros.90

What is particularly interesting about the State aid control system—unlike the free movement provisions—is that when the EU intervenes to enforce the prohibition on State aid under Article 107(1) of the TFEU, the result is that the MS concerned is required to recover from the beneficiaries the tax revenue lost due to the granting of the State aid. Ironically, Ireland (alongside Apple Sales International Ltd and Apple Operations International Ltd) contested the existence of State aid, despite the fact that the 13 billion euros in question should now be paid into Ireland’s public coffers following the Court of Justice’s ruling. For a company of Apple’s size, such a recovery should not pose significant financial difficulties. However, from a national perspective, this sum could substantially improve some of Ireland’s common welfare issues.

Moreover, this recent ruling in the Apple case confirms earlier predictions about the evolving nature of the State aid control system.91 State aid in the form of advance tax rulings that endorse complex and sophisticated intra-group arrangements, which significantly reduce the corporate tax base of large companies, are now facing increased scrutiny and potential restrictions. The comprehensive efforts undertaken by the Commission between 2014 to 2016 have proven to be effective. As a result, even though MS may be reluctant to agree on approximating their laws on corporate taxation through EU law, the negative harmonization enforced through the State aid control system exerts pressure on them to align their income tax laws at the EU level and avoid the burdens associated with the enforcement of the State aid prohibition.

Joana Pedroso is a senior lecturer at the Law Department of the University of Gothenburg.

Per Article 108(2) and (3) of the TFEU.

Case C-465/20 P, Commission v Apple Sale International Ltd. And others.

Ibid, paras. 260–267.

Ibid, paras. 351–366. Also, in Article 16(1) of the Regulation 2015/1589.

See reference to these articles in footnotes 54 and 55.